The Permanent Settlement of Land – IASPOINT

The Permanent Settlement of Land

Cornwallis’s permanent settlement of land revenue, in the year’1793 , was the most far reaching measure since three-quarters’of the revenue came from the land. The permanent zamindari’settlements were made in Bengal, Bihar, Orissa, and Banaras’division of U.P. This settlement was further extended in 1800’to northern Carnatic (north-eastern part of Madras) and the’north-western provinces (eastern U.P.). It covered roughly 19%’of the total area of British India.

The mahalwari tenure was introduced in major portion’of U.P., the Punjab (with some variations) and the central’provinces; while in Awadh, villages were placed under a taluqdar’or middleman with whom the government dealt directly. This’system covered nearly’30%’of the British controlled area.

The ryotwari settlements were made in major portions’of Bombay, Madras and Sindh province. The principles of’this system were also subsequently applied to Assam and’Burma.

What Should I know for My UPSC Exams?

Zamindari System

The main features of “settlement” in the zamindari areas were

Thus, the land revenue collector became a landlord, subject’to the threat that the lands he administered could be sold for’arrears, while the tiers of lesser landholders became his tenants.’The zamindar reaped the profit of rising prices and of cultivation’of wasteland, while the classes below him lost their occupancy’rights. Some of the consequences of this were:

The Company hoped that the zamindari class would not only’be a revenue-generating instrument but serve as intermediaries’for the political dominance of their rule, preserving local custom’and protecting rural life from the possibly rapacious influences’of its own representatives. The first part of this hope was realised’as the zamindars became a conservative interest group in Indian’society. But it imposed an excessive burden on the peasantry as’the fixation of revenue had no scientific basis and was ad hoc.’Further, there was a tendency of Company officials and Indian’landlords to force their tenants into plantation-style farming of’cash crops like indigo and cotton rather than rice and wheat.’This was a contributory factor in many of the worst famines of’the nineteenth century.

In this system even the zamindars faced problems. Their’zamindaries were often auctioned for non-payment of revenue.’This encouraged a new group of people to become zamindars.’The urban merchants, speculators, money lenders, etc., bought’zamindaries. This group had no permanent interests in the’development of land or the welfare of peasantry. As a result a’number of peasant uprisings took place in this region. Some’examples of such uprisings were in 1795 in Panchet, 1798 in’Raipur, 1799 in Balasore and in 1799-1800 in villages around’Midnapore. As a consequence of such trends most zamindars’eventually became absentee landlords, and tended to neglect’investment on the land, with adverse impact on agricultural’development of the country.

Ryotwari System

In Madras, Sir Thomas Munro retained the paternal framework’of government but introduced a radically differing method of’revenue management known as the ryotwari system, in which

Basically, the raiyatwari system was more pragmatic than’doctrinal. By this time the local chiefs were mostly eliminated’or reduced to insignificance. The contact of the administration’with each individual farmer, implied in the raiyatwari system’appeared more conducive to the interest of the state, which’could itself assess the cultivated area and the income of the’tax payer, and which could itself carry out the collection of’taxes. This system also had the advantage for the peasant that’he would be liberated from the oppressive domination of a big’land owner. Lastly this system had less impact on the customs’and social balances of the rural areas.

In western India, Mountstuart Elphinstone attempted’to reconcile the restive populace of the peshwa’s dominions to’British control.

Mahalwari system

In the north of the Company’s dominions, Charles Metcalfe’discovered the largely autonomous village with its joint’ownership of land and cultivation by caste groupings. He’believed this to be the original pattern of rural organisation’throughout India, and he tried to preserve it as far as possible’in current conditions. Like several other administrators of the’period, he was suspicious of change and wished to leave the’villagers alone as far as possible.

He was strongly supported by the work of Holt MacKenzie,’a Bengal ICS official whose memorandum of 1819 set a course’of recognition and record of village rights for the whole of the’north-western provinces and, as later revised and codified,’marked the end of the Bengal system of permanent revenue’settlement in this region.

This was the basis of the mahalwari system introduced’in 1822, with the estate or mahals which were considered’proprietary bodies, where lands belonged jointly to the village’community technically called the ‘body of co-shares’. The’body of co-shares was jointly responsible for the payment of’land revenue though individual responsibility was not left out’completely. In a typically mahalwari village, the co-sharers were’the actual cultivators.

Nature and impact of the new system

The resulting system of administration of British India was still’substantially Indian in pattern, though British direction and’superintendence was superimposed on it. It was paternalistic’and hierarchical, and it suffered, like its predecessors, from’a chronic tendency to over-assess the revenue demand. The’Mughal emperor was replaced by the mystical entity that came’to be known among the common people as the ‘Company’Bahadur’, and its representative, the governor-general, moved’about with almost the same pomp and splendour as was’associated with the Mughal Emperors. At higher levels the’conduct and direction were exclusively European, but the’officers acted in the Mughal spirit, and the administration at’sub district and village level went on much as before.

There were also major changes in the socio-economic’pattern. The British established on a national scale the idea of’property in land, and the resulting buying and selling caused’large class changes. Their new security benefited the commercial’classes generally, but the deliberate sacrifice of Indian industry’to the claims of the new machine industries of Britain ruined’such ancient crafts as cotton and silk weaving. The new legal’system, with its network of courts, proved efficient on the’criminal justice side but was heavily overloaded on the civil.

The strains and the problems caused by this situation created’a demand for increased Indian role in the administration and’caused the first cracks in the British monopoly of higher office.’Indianisation began specifically with the obvious inefficiencies’of the British legal system. The picture was completed by the’company’s army, separately organised in the three presidencies’and officered, like the civil service, exclusively by the British. It’was backed by contingents of the British army. The Bengal army’preponderated in numbers and fighting spirit. By European’standards it was cumbrous and inefficient; but it was still more’than a match for anything that could be brought against it.

Exit mobile version